The theory behind cost sharing is that it should deter ineffective care. In reality, it is a blunt and crude instrument that places barriers in front of effective care as well as ineffective care. I want to highlight two papers that I’ve read recently for some projects at work that will hopefully generate a couple of good papers.
The first examines IUD utilization. It found that the pre-ACA up-front cost-sharing deterred utilization:
Results: Overall, 5.5% of women initiated an IUD in 2011. After adjustment, IUD initiation was less likely among women with higher versus lower co-pays (adjusted risk ratio = 0.65; 95% CI, 0.64–0.67). Women who saw an obstetrician/gynecologist during 2011 were more likely to initiate an IUD (adjusted risk ratio = 2.49; 95% CI, 2.45–2.53).
IUD’s are fix it and forget it contraception. Once an IUD is inserted correctly, it is very difficult for it to fail. It gives significant female autonomy and over the long run of its effective use span, an IUD is less expensive and more reliable than oral hormonal contraception. The big problem pre-ACA with insurers discouraging IUD utilization is that there is a high initial up-front cost which means that a significant portion of the women would experience significant benefits from the IUD including the net cost savings compared to oral contraception after they had stopped paying premiums to the insurer that paid for the IUD. It is a churn problem.
There is another set of problems that come from inefficient cost sharing designs. It is the non-adherance of effective and high value treatment problem From one of the same authors, an examination of medication adherence for a long term cancer (Chronic Myeloid Leukemia (CML)) treatment regime that has impressive survival effects.
Over the study period, the mean copayment required for a 30-day supply of imatinib was $108 (SD, $301). Mean copayments varied widely, with patients in the lowest 25th percentile paying $17 and those in the upper 75th percentile paying $53. Importantly, the median copayment required across all years was approximately $30 per fill, but copayments ranged from $0 to $4,792. Over time, monthly copayments increased from an average of $55 in 2002 to $145 in 2010….
Among new users of imatinib, approximately 10% of patients with relatively lower copayment requirements and 17% of patients with higher copayments discontinued therapy during the first 180 days following treatment initiation (Table 2). There was a 70% increase in the risk of discontinuing TKIs among patients with higher copayment requirements (upper 75th percentile; aRR, 1.70; 95% CI, 1.30 to 2.22). Similarly, approximately 21% of patients with lower copayments were nonadherent to their TKI therapy ( 80% of days with drug available) versus 30% of patients with higher copayments. Patients with higher copayments were 42% more likely to be nonadherent to their TKI therapy (aRR, 1.42; 95% CI, 1.19 to 1.69)…..
Okay, there is a lot going on in that results section. The important take-away is that cancer patients with higher co-payments are far more likely to be non-adherent. This is financial toxicity, a concept advanced by one of my Duke Margolis colleagues, Dr. Yousuf Zafar. The cost of treatment forces people away from getting the care that they need.
People don’t elect to have cancer. It is not an episode that is immediately deferrable. Once you’re told that you have cancer, treatment usually needs to get started quickly. And the effective drugs are expensive. At this point the idea of cost sharing as a means of shaping choices and avoiding preventable conditions goes out the window. It is merely a burden sharing between the insurer and the individual. It is just a financial shock with no positive incentive effect when an individual is hit with a dozen other life altering shocks at the same time.
If we are trying to design a system that minimizes non-adherence for financial reasons, we want to change the benefit design. A theoretically attractive solution would be to offer no cost sharing on effective but expensive courses of treatment for diseases that are not immediately preventable. This would be a value based insurance design approach. VBID encourages people to get effective care by making it comparatively less expensive than ineffective care or care for preventable episodes.
There is a problem with a VBID approach. It is an ugly selection problem. Let’s imagine that there are two types of plans offered. The first is a standard plan design with high cost sharing for imatinib (Gleevac). The other is a low or no cost-sharing design for imatinib. Individuals who are healthy at the start of open enrollment period will choose the standard plan. Individuals who have CML will go to the low cost sharing pool. An individual who was healthy at open enrollment and then is diagnosed with CML during the first policy year will switch over. This incentive structure makes the VBID pool extremely sick.
Sick pools are not show stoppers. There are tools that can be used to compensate insurers with sick pools. The most common is risk adjustment where money from either other insurers with healthy pools or the general government funds are sent to the insurers with disproportionate number of CML patients to cover the high and recurring costs. And given that the VBID design is meant to encourage more people to take more of a very expensive drug, the costs will be higher than the baseline average CML patient cost. Reinsurance tied to specific diagnosis could work as well.
The other option is to mandate benefit designs that are based on VBID principles for high cost diseases. States could do this on their individual and fully insured group markets but they can’t touch the ERISA regulated employer sponsored self-insured segment. We would still have a serious churn problem as people with expensive chronic conditions would still be moving between ESI and Exchanges and given the differences in after treatment incomes, these people will be far stickier to their preferred option than healthy people.
Benefit design right now is complex, confusing and ineffective at promoting health in the CML case. Any changes will also be complex and confusing but hopefully more effective at enabling better health.
** Pace, L. E., Dusetzina, S. B., Fendrick, A. M., Keating, N. L., & Dalton, V. K. (2013). The Impact of Out-of-Pocket Costs on the Use of Intrauterine Contraception Among Women With Employer-sponsored Insurance. Medical Care, 51(11), 959-963. doi:10.1097/mlr.0b013e3182a97b5d
*** Dusetzina, S. B., Winn, A. N., Abel, G. A., Huskamp, H. A., & Keaton, N. L. (2013). Cost Sharing and Adherence to Tyrosine Kinase Inhibitors for Patients With Chronic Myeloid Leukemia. Journal of Clinical Oncology. Retrieved August 4, 2017.
Central Planning
Aren’t employers with multiple insurance offerings causing this problem too? For example, pregnancy – it’s certainly not deferrable. When we were getting ready to have our first kid (January birthday), I’m sure we switched from a lower cost, higher co-pay plan to the higher cost, lower co-pay plan because we know we would have a hospital visit, and it was significantly less expensive to us to switch plans.
Today, knowing our healthcare needs (with 5 kids), we’re on the high deductible plan because we know we max out the deductible. We’ve been in co-insurance territory for 6 weeks, and expect to be co-pay free in another month.
The different plans let me maximize the benefit to me, not the insurance pool. Isn’t that a counter-productive cost sharing (from an insurance company POV)?
Bradley
Dave
If an RA model worked as intended, i.e., its explanatory powers were >90-95% (go with it), would plan differentiation be feasible? Low-cost plans would pay high-cost plans, and in the long run, premiums would adjust and balance. We would have a state of equilibrium.
Brad
David Anderson
@Bradley: Handwaving perfect Risk Adjustment (RA) would solve a lot of problems. I don’t think perfect risk adjustment in this context would solve the immediate concern of encouraging people to get the most effective (clinically and financially) long run treatment. As a second or third order play it would help a lot by removing the flee the market because of a death spiral problem.
But her emails!!!
So in brief:
If you’re an insurer and certain behaviors/health related expenditures actually save you money in the long run, you shouldn’t engage in stupid, self-defeating behaviors like charging co-pays on those expenditures.
Yarrow
@But her emails!!!:
They just hope you’ll be some other insurer’s problem before the expensive health problems show up. That way they never have to pay for either the preventative testing/medication or the treatment.
Even with people who have half reasonable insurance our system is dumb. Your deductibles start all over at the beginning of the year just as holiday charges roll in. I know I’m not alone in delaying going to the doctor or having a more expensive test done because I have to start over with deductibles.
Villago Delenda Est
The principal problem with an IUD is that the slut can’t get pregnant to be punished for her agency.
MoxieM
I can see why an IUD is a good example for the issue you’re presenting. But I also feel compelled to note that for a great many women they are anything but a “fix and forget” option. Notwithstanding the improvement in IUD design (Dalkon shield, anyone?), they carry risks of their own, especially to those of us who have Endometriosis. $.02
StringOnAStick
@MoxieM: This is a good example of the “art” side of medicine. For some women an IUD is as David describes, and for others it is not. This is why medicine can’t be a set of”if X, do Y” algorithms, as much as certain industry players want it to be. I knew a doctor who said that every time anyone takes a pill of has a procedure done it is an experiment; one that usually has the expected outcome but 100% results isn’t a given at all.
Villago Delenda Est
@StringOnAStick: Finance dudes hate art. They want predictability. Unfortunately, the universe is more complicated than that.
Raoul
I’m curious about dealing with HIV.
I have friends who are long-term positive and on treatment regimens. I’d imagine the prescription costs are high but also pretty predictable (and non-treatment would later yield very expensive care and high morbidity).
On vacation, these friends were recently chatting about the differences in MN vs CO, but all were getting co-pay help from the drug companies to stay on their meds. All have decent to good jobs with company health insurance. If big pharma can make enough money on the net price of the drugs to be able to cover the co-pays, why are there co-pays?
It’s another dumb inefficiency in the ‘market-based’ approach to insurance/care, IMO.
Animouse
I’m an oncology nurse. Leukemia is my specialty. The really stupid part is that patients who do not take their TKIs correctly can develop resistance to all of the available agents and progress to acute leukemia. This calls for about a month in the hospital getting chemo and then a stem cell transplant. Then they can easily become million dollar patients.
David Anderson
@Raoul: Because in this instance there are two things going on. First, the copay is merely another means of the insurer trying to select away from covering HIV patients and/or get the patients to pay for a percentage of fixed costs. They would prefer that there are no copay assistance programs as that would give them a stronger public negotiating position for lower drug prices as more people will publicly scream. Secondly, there are people who can’t, won’t or not consistently access the copay assistance programs.